Problems in the housing market stem from decisions made in the early democratic era that handed Taiwan’s urban environment over to developers at the expense of first-time home buyers
The Taipei Times reported last week that housing transactions fell 15.3 percent last month, to under 20,000 units. However, the market boomed for the first eight months of the year, and observers expect it to show growth for the year as a whole.
The fall was due to Central Bank intervention.
LANDOWNERS COMPLAIN
Why is it so difficult to obtain houses at low prices even though Taiwan is overbuilt? Some of the issues I have explored before. But another factor in the housing price explosion is land planning decisions made early in the democratic era that have handed Taiwan’s urban “planning” over to developers.
A Rutgers-based scholar, Mi Shih (史宓), has written a series of papers on planning and the conversion of the domestic economy to a real-estate based economy. According to Shih, the story begins in the 1970s with the issue of land zoned as reserved land (保留地) — that is, land for public facilities such as roads and parks, which could not be developed. However, the law required that private landowners whose land becomes reserved land be compensated, but in the Martial Law era, there was no legal requirement to pay in the short term. Hence, local governments routinely delayed or refused to pay. Shih instances a 1988 estimate showing that “Taiwan had nearly 41,000 hectares of reserved land in total, with a compensatory cost almost double that of all Taiwanese governmental budgets combined.”
This blew up into a crisis because the law required that all reserved land compensation be paid out by September of 1988 or else the land would be de-zoned. The legislature amended the Urban Planning Act (都市計畫法) to remove that requirement, and landowners began to yell, “generating a roaring grassroots discontent to which the rapidly democratizing Taiwanese government could not turn a deaf ear,” Shih says.
That was also the time when the Snails Without Shells protests over suddenly rising housing prices were taking place.
TRANSFERABLE DEVELOPMENT RIGHTS
As in so many policymaking situations, planners looked to the US for solutions, borrowing the idea of transferable development rights (TDR). In American practice, the government often gives TDRs to landowners and developers to facilitate planned development that extends beyond the property they own. Major cities that use this approach carefully monitor and manage it to keep cities compact and reduce community objections.
Shih says that Taiwanese planners intended to use TDRs to get developers to finance government compensation for reserved land. However, the Taiwanese TDR model, known as “floating TDR,” does not require government-designated receiving sites and gives developers great legal freedom to build TDR projects almost anywhere. Developers simply “move” the permitted floor space from the public reserved lands to their projects, often exceeding local density limits. Shih adds that “3,764 development projects have utilized TDR since the early 2000s, generating 807 hectares of floor area in excess of existing density limits — roughly equivalent to adding 100,875 new, market-rate apartments.”“The sad thing is that in New Jersey, for the most part, our politicians — especially at the legislative and county level — they don’t know what campaigning means,” said Julia Sass Rubin
This freedom from regulatory restriction means that local governments do not capture most of the land value created by building construction. It goes to developers, a massive hidden subsidy to land development. Community input in this process is entirely lacking, an example of the way early democratic era regulators retained the mindset of the authoritarian era.
In a later paper Shih and Chang Ying-hui (江穎慧) at National Chengchi University show how the TDR approach, coupled with formulaic density calculations, produce urban landscapes in Taiwan, land speculation and commodification, and the current real-estate driven economy. When they calculate the value of land, developers know what density numbers will be permitted by the government. These they treat as extra profit. Together, TDR practices and density valuations drive increased land brokerage and land transactions, pushing up prices. This creates, they contend, a “financially more calculable urban world in which capital’s acquisitive appetite for land’s monetary value is intensified.” Moreover, Shih and Chang argue, because these approaches are viewed by planners, developers and the public at large as purely technical decisions, they escape political scrutiny.
Worse, in yet another paper on Taiwan TDR practices, Shih and colleagues observe that TDR projects push up the value of nearby residential properties as well, making homes for lower income groups even less affordable.
It should now be obvious why the Central Bank is tinkering with the interest rates to cool down the housing market: interest rate changes have no effect on the political economy of residential development, and on the legal arrangements that favor developers over all other players in the market.
The Central Bank’s intervention exists solely to keep the market from exploding and then collapsing, a way of keeping a permanent crisis from spinning out of control — like so many other government interventions in Taiwan’s numerous permanent crises.